Chuka resident makes a point during a public participation forum in Tharaka Nithi County. [Phares Mutembei, Standard]

Kenya is currently doing a very delicate balancing act between debt repayments and further investment in development projects. Regarding domestic borrowing, it is instructive that it will necessitate an increase in interest rates. This is how it works. For the government to attract citizens to lend money to it on a short-term basis, and not save the same in commercial banks, the government raises interest rates on Treasury Bills beyond what financial institutions can offer to customers on their deposits.

This process is called open market operation. When this happens, the commercial banks and other financial institutions are denied deposits which are instead directed to the Central Bank of Kenya to buy the bills. This leads to what economists call 'crowding out effect", where financial institutions are starved of cash to lend to borrowers, thus leading to poor performance of the financial sector.

When financial institutions reduce their lending activities, households and firms have less money available to them for investment. This leads to poor economic activity. The economy produces fewer goods and services. The economy cannot create enough jobs to accommodate all the job-seekers who are leaving schools, tertiary institutions and universities. With fewer goods being produced by the economy relative to the money supply, inflation becomes a natural consequence.

Inflationary spirals

No government wants to deliberately instigate inflationary spirals beyond the levels that make economic sense. In the circumstances, increased borrowing from external sources is not only economically imprudent, but also difficult. Further indebtedness is, therefore, not a good option. Domestic borrowing is equally not a very good alternative given the poor state of the economy. Effective mobilisation of domestic financial resources, therefore, remains the most viable source of budget financing in the current situation.

That said, the government should proceed to clearly explain, item by item, the basis of choosing the specific revenue streams for inclusion in the budget, how much revenue is expected from them, the socio-economic implications of such revenue sources, and mitigation measures.

One of the contentious issues that the opposition is raising is that the government is raiding the poor man's purse by imposing more taxes on fuel and other basic needs that will have a far reaching multiplier effect on the economy, with the expected result being further increase in the cost of living.

In this regard, the government should explain to Kenyans how taxing them more in the short-run is a better option than borrowing very expensive loans at commercial rates from external sources. More specifically, the government must demonstrate, through a cost-benefit analysis that if the taxes generated from domestic sources are prudently put to use, Kenyans stand to benefit much more than when expensive offshore loans are borrowed.

I can already foresee a problem here. Kenyans have had a very bad experience with past regimes regarding the linkage between taxation and service provision. It will take a lot of convincing for Kenyans to accept that this government represents a departure from past largesse and malfeasance associated with its predecessors.

The other issue regarding the choices of budgetary items is the nature of the goods, needs they satisfy, and why choosing them for inclusion in the budget is a novel idea. Economists have many categories of goods. For our purpose, let us look at only three of them, namely, Giffen goods, Sin goods and Veblen goods. Giffen goods are low-income, non-luxury products that defy standard economic and consumer demand theory.

 President Ruto with his deputy Rigathi Gachagua at Kenya Revenue Authority during a past event. [PSCU]

Typically, when the price of a product increases, the demand for it is expected to reduce. The demand for Giffen goods does not follow this rule. Instead, the demand goes up as the prices increase. This is because as the price increases, consumers begin to foresee shortage of the product. So, consumers buy more and more of it to cushion themselves against future shortages. This consumer behaviour pushes the price even further. Examples of Giffen goods in Kenya include ugali, bread and milk.

An increase in taxation of any of the Giffen goods will definitely push up the cost of living for the majority of Kenyans. The government must really demonstrate that it has run out of options for it to resort to taxing Giffen goods in a country where more than 50 per cent of citizens can hardly afford a square meal per day. At the same time, the government must leave no iota of doubt in the minds of Kenyans that it has put in place the necessary safeguards to cushion vulnerable members of society.

Sin goods are those goods whose consumption is considered harmful to society. They include beer, tobacco products, spirits, candies, soft drinks, and wines. The tax levied on them is called "Sin Tax." In Kenya, sin tax is levied in the form of excise duties. The unique characteristic of sin goods is that their consumption does not vary with price.

For example, if the price of beer is increased by Sh5, its consumption may not change. The demand for sin goods is said to be inelastic, that is, a change in price does not cause a corresponding change in demand. The government uses taxation of sin goods as a good tax policy instrument because of minimal variability between target and actual tax revenues.

Veblen goods, like Giffen goods, defy the normal operations of the supply and demand mechanism. Veblen goods are high income, luxury goods whose demand increases with increases in prices. They include luxury cars, high-end jewelry and designer clothing items.

Economists refer to them as goods of ostentation. They are consumed by the very opulent members of society. This category of consumers is capable of hitting back if it becomes apparent that the government is unnecessarily targeting them to raise more tax revenues. Consumers of Veblen goods are capable of mobilising legislators to do their bidding on tax matters.

The issue of low-cost decent housing scheme must equally be debated openly, and especially the issues of compulsory levy, target beneficiaries, role of government in the process, and who will manage the projects. These assurances are necessary to avoid long protracted court cases. There has also been talk about huge increases in customs duty on selected imported products. The government should be able to demonstrate that increased duty is meant to protect local industries by discouraging importation of second-hand products.

After the government lays bare the thinking behind its taxation plan for the current financial year, the opposition and other stakeholders must be allowed ample time to digest the presentations so that they can come up with well-considered responses to them. Then the consensus building should ensue.

At the end of it, Kenyans should get a budget that not only represents their collective objective interests and aspirations, but also makes sense to them, and has the potential to catapult the country towards attaining its Vision 2030 of becoming a middle-level income economy.

The government, on its part, must undertake to be transparent in its development priorities. Kenyans need a budget that takes care of all of them, irrespective of their ethnicity, political orientation, gender, religion or circumstances. Kenyans need an all-inclusive government; a government that they can all relate to, and consider their own.

It can be achieved through goodwill and consensus building across the political divide.
Let's give consensus building a chance.

Prof Ongore teaches at the Technical University of Kenya and is a former chief manager at Kenya Revenue Authority. vincent.ongore@tukenya.ac.ke